Results of the Bounded Resource Model
A church which relies on a resource alone to generate its growth will always be limited as that resource becomes harder to produce. The resource may include paid staff, lay ministries, spiritual life, social engagement, social capital, social networks, reputation and legitimacy.
Limit Determined by Resource
Consider a church of initially 10 people with a total leaving rate of 6% per year, including deaths. Church members are assumed to be very effective at building the resource, enabling growth at 19 recruits per year per resource unit. However, the resource starts low, at 12% of capacity, due to the small size of the church. The resource is an easily depletable one at 50% per year. It is built at a rate of 0.0075 per person per year, assuming there is no resistance from the resource itself to its building.
Such a highly effective church grows over 60 years to get near its equilibrium value of 250. This is an upper limit that becomes increasingly harder to approach due to the difficulty in generating the resource, figure 1.
Initially, the growth of the church accelerates as the recruitment reinforcing loop has the strongest impact on the church. By time 20, this impact has fallen so that the leaving loop dominates, figure 1. Church growth now slows. The slowing period is much longer than the acceleration period and occurs when the church is 85 much less than half its final equilibrium value. When growth is through a resource, the pattern is often not symmetric, with most of the church growth coming while it is slowing down.
The resource follows a similar pattern, figure 2, and approaches its equilibrium at 79% of its possible maximum faster than the church tends to its limit.
For the first 10 years, growth in the resource accelerates as resource generation has the highest impact. This is the same reinforcing loop that causes the church’s growth. However, its dominance ceases 10 years before it ceases on the church. Thus, the resource starts slowing down before the church number. If the resource is measurable, then its slowing down could be used as an advanced warning that the church’s growth will slow in the future.
If the resource is interpreted as spiritual life, then the church could be deemed to be in revival while that resource is increasing faster. Revival would then be seen to be over when the spiritual life is slowing down. In this case, the revival has ended before the church growth has slowed down. If the church’s attention is on the growth in numbers rather than in life, then it may not realise that the revival has waned for a few years. This may be quite applicable to charismatic renewal, whose churches had carried on growing for some time even though the life in the churches and conferences had stopped increasing rapidly.
At time 10, the combination of two balancing feedback loops, the “brake” and depletion, dominates, and the increase in resource starts slowing down, figure 2. The “brake” is the increasing difficulty of generating the resource as it gets large. It can be shown that this increasing difficulty is the cause of the church reaching a limit, not that actual bound on the resource. At 79% the resource has stopped well short of this bound.
The impacts of the three loops on the resource are given in figure 3—the vertical line at time 10 indicates where loop dominance on the resource changes. The impact of the loop on resource measures its force on the resource, measured relative to its rate of change. The net impact is a measure of the curvature of the graph. Note the impact of resource generation, curve 1, initially drops but then starts increasing again. It is a positive impact. However, the brake, curve 2, increases in magnitude faster, and together with the constant depletion impact, more than counters the resource generation. Thus, the increasing difficulty of resource generation is the source of slowing resource and slowing the church’s growth.
Extinction Through Lack of Resource Generation
Consider a church whose equilibrium value is 70 with resource just over 50%. After 20 years, let the ability to generate the resource drop to 40% of the equilibrium value, perhaps due to the loss or unavailability of key personnel. The church is tipped into extinction, with equilibrium now at zero, figure 4. Initially, the resource declines sharply, then slows to a modest fall. The church declines steadily for the next 80 years to have 17 remaining members. If ageing had been taken into account, the decline in the last 40 years would be much sharper.
Thus, reduction in resource generation could be a cause of congregational decline. It is not that the resource generation has ceased at time 20, but that it has fallen below a critical level that would have avoided extinction. Perhaps the prayer meetings have become poorly attended, and spiritual life generation is reduced. Perhaps the church is advertising itself less, for example, discontinuing a regular home leaflet drop. Perhaps it has reduced its presence in the local street pastors or food bank. Perhaps it no longer provides refreshments after services, thus reducing networking opportunities. Perhaps it has reduced “capacity” at services by having less services at varying times. These give some ideas of how a church may reduce resource generation and tip itself into future extinction.
Thus, a reduction in resource generation could be a cause of congregational decline. It is not that the resource generation has ceased at time 20, but that it has fallen below a critical level that would have avoided extinction. Perhaps, for example,
- The prayer meetings have become poorly attended, and spiritual life generation is reduced.
- The church is advertising itself less, for example, discontinuing a regular home leaflet drop.
- The church may have reduced its presence in the local street pastors or food bank.
- The church no longer provides refreshments after services thus reducing networking opportunities.
- The church may have reduced “capacity” at services by having fewer services at varying times.
These examples give some ideas of how a church may reduce resource generation and tip itself into future extinction.
Secularisation
The effect of secularisation on church growth can be illustrated in this model by allowing the number recruited per resource to drop as secularisation rises. This scenario reflects the increasing difficulty the church has convincing a more hardened population to become believers, assuming the resource remains the same. In addition, the effect of secularisation on the church can be modelled by allowing the depletion rate of the resource to rise. This represents the pressures on society for church members to be less committed to the church and, thus, less committed to resource production.
Consider a church with the same parameter values as figures 1-3, starting with a size of 10. The parameters remain constant for 45 years after which secularisation starts and increases steadily until 150 years in total have elapsed. The effect on the church is given in figure 5. Note at 45 years the church, line 1, is still short of its equilibrium, line 2, although its growth is slowing. Despite the effects of secularisation, the church continues to grow until time 60, as secularisation has not reduced the accumulated resource sufficiently to initiate decline. From time 60 onwards, the church starts to decline with the equilibrium value is well below the church numbers at any given time. Church decline is moderate, not dramatic, as both the church and the resource are accumulations and take time to reduce. At time 125 the church equilibrium has dropped below zero, indicating the church is now heading for extinction, even though it will still take many years to reach that point.
Once the equilibrium value, line 2, has fallen below the current value of the church, line 1, the church has accelerated decline. This is caused by the reinforcing loop R, the recruitment link. Once the recruitment rate falls below the leaving rate, loop R has a negative effect on church numbers, and its brief dominance accelerates the decline. Once its effect is positive again leaving dominates and the decline is more gradual. The impact of a loop directly affects the curvature of the graph rather than its numbers, which are influenced indirectly.
Once secularisation starts, time 45, the resource quickly drops as it is much closer to its equilibrium/saturation value. The resource continues to drop, lagging its equilibrium value. As that equilibrium value becomes zero, it can be concluded that the church heads for extinction as its resource generation is heading for zero.
The R feedback loop (generation) briefly dominates, as it has a negative effect. Then the brake is largest as church numbers are still high, eventually assisted by the depletion loop as church numbers drop. The resource continues to curve downwards because of the effect of secularisation on the church.
Strategies to Raise Limit to Growth
This model suggests 5 strategies that raise the limit on church numbers.
1. Fewer Resources Done Well is Better than Many Resources Done Poorly
Easy-to-generate resources with little potential to recruit should be avoided. For example, a few high-quality social engagement projects are better than many projects where the quality and effectiveness suffers.
2. Do Not Rely on One Resource Alone
Relying on one resource for most of the growth is risky. If, for any reason, factors outside the church’s control affect that resource, for example, a sudden loss of reputation, a key pastor, or Sunday school teachers, then there is no alternative driver of growth. Thus, two or three good resources enable a church to get through a difficult patch if one of those resources is suffering.
3. Improve the Quality of the Resource Before its Quantity
Give due attention to improving the effectiveness of the resource. The parameter number recruited per year per resource is more sensitive than the resource generated per person. Thus, improvements in the effectiveness of the resource will have more effect on growth than generating more of the resource. For example, a higher quality Sunday School that attracts more people is better than just making it bigger. The higher quality, which gives higher church recruitment, will naturally increase church size. Likewise, improvements in the quality of pastoral care, the sort that people outside the church find helpful, will aid growth more than just making more care available.
4. Reduce the Leaving Rate
Closing the back door of the church always helps raise the capacity limit of the church. A lower leaving rate makes the resource more effective on net growth.
5. Prevent Resource Depletion
Many resources are depleted. People leave the church for natural reasons, leaving Bible studies, Sunday Schools, social programmes etc. But others leave due to events in the church that hurt them, hinder them serving God etc. Good pastoral care of people will help reduce this resource depletion and, of course, make more contented people. As the church grows, the likelihood of such adverse effects on people increases, and leaders should be on the lookout for early signs of difficulties.